Skip to main content

PERSPECTIVE article

Front. Public Health, 06 March 2024
Sec. Health Economics
This article is part of the Research Topic Reviews in Public Health Expenditure and Performance View all 9 articles

Aligning opportunity cost and net benefit criteria: the health shadow price

  • School of Health and Society, University of Wollongong, Wollongong, NSW, Australia

Given constrained healthcare budgets and many competing demands, public health decision-making requires comparing the expected cost and health outcomes of alternative strategies and associated adoption and financing actions. Opportunity cost (comparing outcomes from the best alternative use of budgets or actions in decision making) and more recently net benefit criteria (relative valuing of effects at a threshold value less costs) have been key concepts and metrics applied toward making such decisions. In an ideal world, opportunity cost and net benefit criteria should be mutually supportive and consistent. However, that requires a threshold value to align net benefit with opportunity cost assessment. This perspective piece shows that using the health shadow price as the ICER threshold aligns net benefit and opportunity cost criteria for joint adoption and financing actions that arise when reimbursing any new strategy or technology under a constrained budget. For an investment strategy with ICER at the health shadow price Bc = 1/(1/n + 1/d-1/m), net benefit of reimbursing (adopting and financing) that strategy given an incremental cost-effectiveness ration (ICER) of actual displacement, d, in financing, is shown to be equivalent to that of the best alternative actions, the most cost-effective expansion of existing programs (ICER = n) funded by the contraction of the least cost-effective programs (ICER = m). Net benefit is correspondingly positive or negative if it is below or above this threshold. Implications are discussed for creating pathways to optimal public health decision-making with appropriate incentives for efficient displacement as well as for adoption actions and related research.

1 Introduction

Optimizing health outcomes from a constrained public health system budget requires decisions about which programs and strategies to support through reimbursement when investing in or allocating budgets and resources. Opportunity cost and net benefit criteria have been key concepts and metrics applied to inform budget-constrained optimal health system decision-making. This review paper introduces opportunity cost (section 2) and net benefit criteria (section 3) and shows how they are aligned using the health shadow price (section 4) as a threshold value for net benefit (section 5). This finding and its implications are discussed in section 6 in relation to creating pathways for optimal resource allocation and investment decisions with joint adoption and financing actions, but also to incentivize research in identifying the best expansion and contraction of programs with constrained budgets.

2 Opportunity cost

Health systems with constrained budgets or resources and unconstrained population health need to make allocative decisions across alternative strategies. Given constrained resources and funding, the opportunity cost of any resource use or reimbursement/investment decision and associated action/s (adoption and financing with reimbursement), is the forgone value of outcomes from the best alternative use or choice and associated set of actions (15).

As a result, all constrained healthcare system funding or resource allocation processes face opportunity costs with each reimbursement or investment decision. That is, the value of the best alternative investment or reimbursement choice with adoption and necessary associated financing actions under a constrained budget.

3 Net benefit criteria

The net benefit is a metric that combines the joint consideration of effects and costs (resource use and their prices) to compare the relative value less cost of strategies, decisions, or action/s (69). For the simplest case of two strategy comparisons, the incremental net benefit (INB) of a strategy relative to a comparator is:

I N B = λ Δ E Δ C     (1)

Where λ is the threshold value for effects and ΔE and ΔC are incremental effects and costs. Positive INB implies invest, while 0 or negative INB implies don’t invest. Net benefit metrics have a series of advantages over incremental cost-effectiveness ratios (ICERs) (917). These include being well ordered when the effect is 0 or changes sign around 0, having an opposite sign consistent with the implications when a strategy is dominated or dominates, and reflecting the degree of any such dominance (9). In addition, additive separability of net benefit (although not ICERs) (10) implies that multiple strategies or multiple domains can be consistently compared relative to any comparator based on maximizing net benefit (NB = λE−C) or equivalently minimizing net loss (NL = λDU + C) under the net benefit correspondence theorem (1117). DU in the net loss metric simply represents any effect/s (E) in net benefit framed from a disutility perspective (e.g., mortality vs. survival, morbidity vs. no morbidity, QALYs lost vs. QALYs gained, etc.).

4 The health shadow price

Given a fixed or constrained budget, the health shadow price represents the critical or threshold value at which the health outcome from any reimbursement decision (adoption and financing action) equates with the best alternative adoption and financing actions (4, 5). The best alternative adoption and financing actions are to implement the most cost-effective expansion of existing programs (ICER = n, e.g., $5,000/QALY) funded by reducing the least cost-effective programs (ICER = m, e.g., $ 1 million/QALY).

Thus, with a constrained budget, for any given investment I with actual displacement (ICER = d, e.g., $20,000/QALY) the health shadow price ( B C ) for any given strategy is found by setting the net health return from reimbursing (adopting and financing) that strategy for any given investment amount I , I / B C I / d , as equal to that from the best alternative joint adoption and financing actions I / n I / m .

Consequently, solving

I B c I d = I n I m

results in:

1 B c = 1 n + 1 d 1 m

or

B c = ( 1 n + 1 d 1 m ) 1     (2)

The subscript c denotes that the health shadow price (Equation 2), like opportunity cost, corresponds to the economic context of the best alternative actions within a constrained budget (4, 5, 18, 19). Explicitly the context for making budget constrained reimbursement (joint adoption and financing) decisions. That is the context of actual displacement (ICER= d), and best alternative expansion (ICER= n) and contraction (ICER= m) actions.

For example, if n = $5,000/QALY, d = $20,000/QALY, and m = $1,000,000/QALY, then

B c = 1 1 5000 + 1 20000 1 1000000 = 1 0.0002 + 0.00005 0.0000001 = 1 0.0002499 = $ 4001.60 / Q A L Y

5 Incremental net benefit consistent with opportunity cost

If we conduct an incremental net benefit assessment of an investment or reimbursement amount I relative to the best alternative investment or reimbursement of I (adoption and financing actions) using the health shadow price as a threshold value then from Equation 1 and Equation 2 we have:

I N B = B C Δ E Δ C

Now for cases of interest where ΔE and ΔC are both positive, i.e., in the NE quadrant, then INB using the health shadow price as a threshold value is only positive where Β c ΔE−ΔC > 0 and hence ΔC/ΔE< Β c or negative where Β c ΔE−ΔC < 0 and hence ΔC/ΔE> Β c . QED.

Hence, using the health shadow price, Β c as the threshold value for effects aligns INB with the same decisions as comparing the investment ICER with the health shadow price—which is derived from and represents the opportunity cost of budget-constrained investments.

6 Discussion: implications for optimal research, resource allocation, and investment

In sections 2–5 we have shown that using the health shadow price as the critical threshold value for incremental net benefit appropriately results in equivalent net benefit between:

i. Any new budget constrained investment (I) in a strategy with ICER equal to the health shadow price funded by displacement (ICER = d) and;

ii. The best alternative health system adoption and financing actions for the same budget constrained investment I.

Furthermore, if the strategy has a lower or higher ICER than this, then its INB is appropriately correspondingly positive or negative.

Importantly this means that for any investment with a constrained budget using the health shadow price as the net benefit threshold value enables net benefit to represent the same rule as opportunity cost.

If the budget was not constrained then investment would only have an adoption action, for which the best alternative action is the most cost-effective expansion of existing programs (ICER = n), which would be the appropriate threshold value. Indeed, this is also the appropriate threshold value for the health shadow price if displacement is efficient (d = m), which is then given by:

B c = ( 1 n + 1 d 1 m ) 1 = 1 1 n = n

In response to experiences in the United Kingdom during the 1990 and 2000s where many services were displaced by the mandated use of medications such as Herceptin (20) different ICER thresholds for displaced services were proposed as a threshold value for INB assessment (2127). Four different displaced service thresholds were proposed:

i. The least cost-effective current program, assuming that this is the program that is actually displaced to finance the additional costs of the new technology (22).

ii. The least cost-effective program, regardless of whether or not it is displaced (23).

iii. The ICER of the services actually displaced to finance that technology regardless of the ICER of that displaced service relative to other services (2426).

iv. The average ICER of historically displaced NHS services (21, 27).

Strictly speaking, these four definitions would only coincide if displacement had been and remained currently efficient (d = m). Nevertheless, the health shadow price makes clear the proposed use of d or any displaced service as a threshold in all its guises (18, 19):

i. Conflates adoption and financing actions—equates the threshold value in expansion with that in contraction (25).

ii. Arises only at a singular point where there is perfect allocative efficiency, but does not provide a pathway to get there.

iii. Most importantly, it denies the true opportunity cost of reimbursing (adopting and funding) new technologies—the most cost-effective expansion of existing health system interventions funded by displacement of the least cost-effective interventions.

Sendi et al. (21) advocated the average ICER of displaced services as a second-best alternative threshold value to the shadow price of the budget constraint reflecting the shadow price per unit of effectiveness in the absence of a market. They emphasized that this, like the shadow price, is a function of program size (5, p.82). Later, theoretical arguments or assertions were made for displaced service-related ICERs representing the shadow price of the budget constraint (2227), explicitly stated in Griffin et al. (25, p.24) as the ICER of actual displaced services, d, with a two-part argument:

i. “Identifying marginal programs that would be displaced and quantifying their cost and health outcomes determines the shadow price of the budget constraint” [SIC].

ii. “The incremental cost per QALY gained of new treatments are commonly compared to some stated threshold λ, which should in principle represent the inverse of the shadow price of the budget constraint” [SIC].

These two parts were combined to argue that any new treatment should be reimbursed if the incremental health offered by the new treatment option exceeds the health foregone with the displacement of marginal programs (25, p.24).

However, in the context of market failure and allocative inefficiency characteristic of the health care system, displaced service definitions in general, and this two-part argument in particular, conflate shadow price in expansion (maximum unit of effect gained as a result of relaxing a constraint by one unit at the margin) (28), with notions of shadow price in contraction (minimum loss when one unit of a continuous resource is withdrawn) (29). Combined, the two parts misrepresent opportunity cost as the actual loss of displacement when the budget is reduced, rather than the highest value alternative (18). Displaced services do not represent opportunity cost, the highest value alternative. If Griffin et al. (25) had appropriately added “in expansion” in part (ii) to represent opportunity cost, it would be clear that this is different from any notion of the shadow price of the budget constraint “in contraction” in part (ii). The only situation in which shadow prices in expansion and contraction can coincide is at the single point of complete allocative efficiency (n = m) and indeed of displacement efficiency (d = m) and hence n = m = d= B c .

Empirically, no health system internationally can claim to beat the point of allocative efficiency. Consider the case of the United Kingdom which was ranked in 2014 by the Commonwealth Fund (30) as having the most efficient health system of high income OECD countries. Despite this international standing, the 2013 evidence from Claxton et al. (27) of the ICER for best expansion (n = 2,000 pounds per QALY), contraction (m = 2.73 million pounds per QALY) and displacement (d = 12,713 pounds per QALY) indicated substantial allocative and displacement inefficiency in practice with n < d < <m (19, 31). This resulted in a health shadow price [following Equation (2)] with 2013 United Kingdom evidence (27) of:

B c = 1 1 2000 + 1 12713 1 2730000 = 1 0.0005 + 0.0000787 0.000000366 = 1 0.0005783 = 1 , 729 pounds / QALY

Pekarsky (5, p.69-83) shows that in the context of such economic inefficiency and market failure for an input, deriving the health shadow price from existing information about the economic context than from cost benefit analysis following McKean (32) and Mishah and Quah (3). That is, the health shadow price (4, 5) as derived in section 4 above, takes into account observed allocative (n < m) and displacement (d < m) inefficiencies, rather than any notion of the shadow price of the budget constraint that assumes perfect economic efficiency.

An underlying inappropriate assumption for health care of complete allocative efficiency in the context of market failure can be traced back to the suggested use of shadow price of the budget constraint as a critical ratio for the threshold value by Weinstein and Zeckerhaus (33). They implicitly assumed complete allocative efficiency (and discrete programs) by suggesting a critical ratio of the cost per effect of the last service financed if all services are ranked and allocated up to the budget—the average shadow price.

As Pekarsky (5, p. 83) surmises: “…health economic focus on the shadow price of the budget constraint…can lead to the following catch 22: we cannot find this shadow price until economic efficiency is achieved, and we cannot achieve economic efficiency until this price is found” [SIC]. Importantly, the health shadow price (4, 5) creates the appropriate incentives for evidence on the best expansion and contraction of current programs to enable it (18, 19). This meets the imperative to “find a shadow price for health effects that will improve economic efficiency rather than being conditional on economic efficiency” [SIC] (5, p. 83). The only point where the health shadow price (4, 5) coincides with the ICER for actual displaced services, d, is at the point of complete allocative (and displacement) efficiency; and because n=m=d=B c only at that singular point. However, using d as a threshold value does not provide a pathway to get there, whereas the health shadow price does (18, 19). That is, the coincidence of the shadow price in expansion and contraction at the single point of allocative efficiency does not provide a pathway to get there from any point of allocative inefficiency. Certainly not when using a displaced service ICER threshold such as d, which is only equal to the health shadow price at the single point of complete allocative efficiency. Moreover, considered dynamically over time with allocative inefficiency (n < m) if displacement were efficient (d = m) then new technologies or strategies priced up to a threshold value of d would be next in line to be displaced and would face additional reversal costs not accounted for in ICER calculations as the new technology cycles through. Hence, as highlighted in Eckermann and Pekarsky (18) use of d as a threshold with appropriate consideration of reversal costs can easily lead to health outcomes from constrained budgets declining over time, particularly if displacement is efficient.

Now, let us consider if comparison of the reimbursement of an investment were not with the best alternative action/s to reflect opportunity costs, but rather with the second best objective of improving the (short term) net benefit from combined adoption and displacement decisions. Then, with a fixed budget the ICER from adopting new programs could be considered relative to that of actual displaced services (21). However, to the extent that displacement is efficient (d approaches m rather than n) this creates a straw man for comparing adoption (even without a budget constraint), let alone if joint adoption and financing actions are appropriately considered together with the health shadow price (18).

The alignment of net benefit with opportunity cost for budget-constrained investment or reimbursement (adoption and financing actions) that arises with the use of the health shadow price ( B C ) as the ICER threshold value does not occur with d (the ICER of displaced services). That is clear noting that generally B c ndm. They only coincide at the single point of complete allocative and displacement efficiency, which no health system internationally satisfies, with n = m = d= B c at this point alone.

This implies that using a threshold value of d for net benefit assessment biases against better use of existing programs or technologies and in favor of pricing new technologies above opportunity cost, given the best alternative reimbursement actions (adoption and financing) that the health shadow price represents.

More generally, in the absence of appropriate incentives created by the health shadow price research decisions are also biased toward evidence for new technologies. On the other hand, there are disincentives for evidence or indeed lack of evidence for unpatented or unpatentable strategies (4, 5, 18, 19). In particular, this would bias against public health strategies such as those for health promotion across the life course (34). Those strategies include community programs that support integrated movement from early childhood to youth, adulthood and older adulthood (3539); successful ageing (4044) or rehabilitation and palliative care services (16, 19, 45). The same types of services that were displaced to accommodate mandated Herceptin use in the United Kingdom highlighted in the 2000s (20).

It could be argued that pharmaceutical and device manufacturing companies are only responsible for adoption and should not be penalized for inefficient displacement (d < m). However, the reality of a constrained budget is that adoption and financing actions (and associated research) for any reimbursement (investment) decision naturally need to occur together. More generally optimal cycles of joint research, reimbursement and regulatory decision making are required to optimize budget-constrained health system outcomes in any jurisdiction and globally (16, 46). Where research funding is biased in favor of new technologies and against unpatentable technologies or programs (e.g., community programs without vested interests), a pathway to optimization requires public policy incentives for research evidence and better use of existing programs and technologies in adoption and displacement (4, 5, 18, 19). Ideally, processes supporting optimal cycles of research, reimbursement and regulatory decision making (16) that systematically reflect and create an imperative for that pathway.

Consequently use the health shadow price as a threshold value for net benefit assessment is key to creating appropriate incentives for research evidence to support displacement or contraction and for appropriate adoption or expansion actions (4, 5, 18, 19). The use of the health shadow price makes it clear that there are joint adoption and financing actions and associated research requirements for any reimbursement/investment decision with constrained budgets.

7 Conclusion

This paper has shown that incremental net benefit aligns with opportunity cost when the health shadow price (section 4) is used as the threshold value. At this threshold value, section 5 showed that the incremental net benefit criteria (section 3) of an investment are positive (negative) only if the health outcomes from that investment are greater (less) than the best alternative adoption and financing actions (opportunity cost section 2). Hence, using the health shadow price as the threshold value for the incremental net benefit assessment in any jurisdiction makes the same reimbursement decision as opportunity cost (section 5). As the discussion in section 6 highlighted, these findings also allow for optimization in resource allocation and investment decisions and appropriate incentives for research in addition to optimal adoption and financing actions.

Data availability statement

The original contributions presented in the study are included in the article/supplementary material, further inquiries can be directed to the corresponding author.

Author contributions

SE conceived and designed the paper and is accountable for all aspects of the work in ensuring that questions related to the accuracy or integrity of any part of the work are appropriately investigated and resolved.

Conflict of interest

The author declares that the research was conducted in the absence of any commercial or financial relationships that could be construed as a potential conflict of interest.

Publisher’s note

All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article, or claim that may be made by its manufacturer, is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.

References

1. Mishan, E. Cost-Benefit Analysis: An Informal Introduction. London: Allen and Unwin (1971).

Google Scholar

2. Birch, S, and Gafni, A. Cost effectiveness/utility analyses: do current decision rules lead us to where we want to be? J Health Econ. (1992) 11:279–96. doi: 10.1016/0167-6296(92)90004-K

Crossref Full Text | Google Scholar

3. Mishan, E, and Quah, E. Cost Benefit Analysis. 5th ed. Abingdon: Routlidge (2007).

Google Scholar

4. Pekarsky, B (2012). Trusts, constraints and the counterfactual: Reframing the political economy of new drugs. PhD Thesis. University of Adelaide.

Google Scholar

5. Pekarsky, BAK. The New Drug Reimbursement Game: A Regulator’s Guide to Playing Ad Wining. London: Springer (2015).

Google Scholar

6. Graham, DA. Cost-benefit analysis under uncertainty. Am Econ Rev. (1981) 1981:715–25.

Google Scholar

7. Graham, DA. Public expenditure under uncertainty: the net-benefit criteria. Am Econ Rev. (1992) 1992:822–46.

Google Scholar

8. Stinnett, AA, and Mullahy, J. Net health benefits: a framework for analysis of uncertainty in cost-effectiveness analysis. Med Dec Making. (1998) 17:483–9.

Google Scholar

9. Willan, A, and Briggs, A. The Statistical Analysis of Cost-effectiveness Data. Chichester: Wiley and Sons (2006).

Google Scholar

10. Stinnett, AA, and Paltiel, AD. Estimating CE ratios under second-order uncertainty—the mean ratio vs the ratio of means. Med Decis Mak. (1997) 17:483–9. doi: 10.1177/0272989X9701700414

PubMed Abstract | Crossref Full Text | Google Scholar

11. Eckermann, S. (2004). “Hospital performance including quality: creating incentives consistent with evidence-based medicine.” PhD Dissertation. UNSW, Sydney. Available at: http://unsworks.unsw.edu.au/vital/access/manager/Repository/unsworks:716

Google Scholar

12. Eckermann, S, Briggs, A, and Willan, A. Health technology assessment in the cost-disutility plane. Med Decis Mak. (2008) 28:172–81. doi: 10.1177/0272989X07312474

Crossref Full Text | Google Scholar

13. Eckermann, S, and Willan, A. 2011. Presenting evidence and summary measures to best inform societal decisions when comparing multiple strategies. PharmacoEconomics. (2011) 29:563–77. doi: 10.2165/11587100-000000000-00000

PubMed Abstract | Crossref Full Text | Google Scholar

14. Eckermann, S, and Coelli, T. Including quality attributes in efficiency measures consistent with net benefit: creating incentives for evidence-based medicine in practice. Soc Sci Med. (2013) 76:159–68. doi: 10.1016/j.socscimed.2012.10.020

PubMed Abstract | Crossref Full Text | Google Scholar

15. McCaffrey, N, Agar, M, Harlum, J, Karnon, J, Currow, D, and Eckermann, S. Better informing decision making with multiple outcomes cost-effectiveness analysis under uncertainty in cost-disutility space. PLoS One. (2015, 2015) 10:e0115544. doi: 10.1371/journal.pone.0115544

PubMed Abstract | Crossref Full Text | Google Scholar

16. Eckermann, S. Health Economics from Theory to Practice: Optimally Informing Joint Decisions of Research, Reimbursement and Regulation with Health System Budget Constraints and Community Objectives. London: Springer (2017).

Google Scholar

17. Eckermann, S, McCaffrey, N, Tonmukayakul, U, Swann, C, and Vella, S. Multiple effects health economic evaluation of the ahead of the game study for mental health promotion in sporting club communities. Heal Econ Rev. (2021) 11:28. doi: 10.1186/s13561-021-00323-1

PubMed Abstract | Crossref Full Text | Google Scholar

18. Eckermann, S, and Pekarsky, B. Can the real opportunity cost stand up: displaced services the straw man outside the room. PharmacoEconomics. (2014). 32:319–25. doi: 10.1007/s40273-014-0140-3

Crossref Full Text | Google Scholar

19. Eckermann, S. The health shadow Price and economically meaningful threshold values. Chapter 11 In: E Simon, editor. Health Economics from Theory to Practice: Optimally Informing Joint Decisions of Research, Reimbursement and Regulation with Health System Budget Constraints and Community Objectives. Cham, Switzerland: Springer (2017)

Google Scholar

20. Barrett, A, Riques, T, Small, M, and Smith, R. How much will Herceptin really cost? Br Med J. (2006) 333:1118–20. doi: 10.1136/bmj.39008.624051.BE

PubMed Abstract | Crossref Full Text | Google Scholar

21. Sendi, P, Gafni, A, and Birch, S. Opportunity costs and uncertainty in the economic evaluation of health care interventions. Health Econ. (2002) 11:23–31. doi: 10.1002/hec.641

Crossref Full Text | Google Scholar

22. Culyer, AJ, McCabe, C, Briggs, A, Claxton, K, Buxton, M, Akehurst, R, et al. Searching for a threshold not setting one: the role of the national institute for health and clinical excellence. J Health Ser Res Policy. (2007) 12:56–8. doi: 10.1258/135581907779497567

Crossref Full Text | Google Scholar

23. McCabe, C, Claxton, K, and Culyer, AJ. The NICE cost-effectiveness threshold: what it is and what that means. PharmacoEconomics. (2008) 26:733–44. doi: 10.2165/00019053-200826090-00004

Crossref Full Text | Google Scholar

24. Claxton, K, Buxton, M, Culyer, A, Walker, S, and Sculpher, M. Value based pricing for NHS drugs: an opportunity not to be missed? BMJ. (2008) 336:251–4. doi: 10.1136/bmj.39434.500185.25

PubMed Abstract | Crossref Full Text | Google Scholar

25. Griffin, S, Claxton, K, and Sculpher, M. Decision analysis for resource allocation in health care. J Health Ser Res Policy. (2008) 13:23–30. doi: 10.1258/jhsrp.2008.008017

Crossref Full Text | Google Scholar

26. Sculpher, M, and Claxton, K. Real economics needs to reflect real decisions. PharmacoEconomics. (2012) 30:133–6. doi: 10.2165/11596660-000000000-00000

Crossref Full Text | Google Scholar

27. Claxton, K, Martin, S, Soares, M, Rice, N, Spackman, E, Hinde, S, et al. (2013). Methods for the estimation of the NICE cost effectiveness threshold final report working paper 82 Centre for Health Economics, University of York.

Google Scholar

28. Mas-Colell, A, Whinston, M, and Green, J. Macroeconomic Theory. New York: Oxford University Press (1995).

Google Scholar

29. Takayama, A. Analytic Methods in Economics. Michigan: Harvester Wheatsheaf. Hemel (1994).

Google Scholar

30. Davis, K, Stremikis, K, Squires, D, and Schoen, C (2014). Mirror, Mirror on the wall, 2014 update: how the U.S. health care system compares internationally. Commonwealth Fund pub no. 1755, 2014.

Google Scholar

31. Eckermann, S. Kinky thresholds revisited: opportunity costs differ in the NE and SW quadrants. Appl Health Econ Health Policy. (2015) 13:7–13. doi: 10.1007/s40258-014-0136-3

PubMed Abstract | Crossref Full Text | Google Scholar

32. McKean, RN. (1972). The use of shadow prices in Cost Benefit Analysis. (ed.) Layard, R (Hammonsworth: Penguin) 119–139

Google Scholar

33. Weinstein, M, and Zeckerhauser, R. Critical ratios and efficient allocation. J Public Econ. (1973) 2:147–57. doi: 10.1016/0047-2727(73)90002-9

Crossref Full Text | Google Scholar

34. World Health Organisation (2017). Best buys and other recommended interventions for the prevention and control of noncommunicable diseases updated (2017), appendix 3 of the global action plan.

Google Scholar

35. Tremblay, MS, Carson, V, Chaput, JP, Connor Gorber, S, Dinh, T, Duggan, M, et al. Canadian 24-hour movement guidelines for children and youth: an integration of physical activity, sedentary, and sleep. Appl Physiol Nutr Metab. (2016) 41:S311–27. doi: 10.1139/apnm-2016-0151

PubMed Abstract | Crossref Full Text | Google Scholar

36. Okely, A, Ghersi, D, Hesketh, KD, Santos, R, Loughran, SP, Cliff, DP, et al. A collaborative approach to adopting/adapting guidelines. The Australian 24-hour movement guidelines for the early years: an integration of physical activity, sedentary behaviour, and sleep. BMC Public Health. (2017) 17:869. doi: 10.1186/s12889-017-4867-6

PubMed Abstract | Crossref Full Text | Google Scholar

37. Ross, R, Chaput, JP, Giangregorio, LM, Janssen, I, Saunders, TJ, Kho, ME, et al. Canadian 24-hour movement guidelines for adults aged 18–64 years and adults aged 65 years or older: an integration of physical activity, sedentary behaviour, and sleep. Appl Physiol Nutr Metab. (2020) 45:S57–S102. doi: 10.1139/apnm-2020-0467

PubMed Abstract | Crossref Full Text | Google Scholar

38. World Health Organisation. Guidelines on Physical Activity, Sedentary Behaviour and Sleep for Children Under 5 Years of Age. Geneva: World Health Organization (2019).

Google Scholar

39. Eckermann, S, Willan, AR, Okely, A, Tremblay, MS, and Coelli, T. Robust cross-country comparison of children meeting 24-hr movement guidelines: an odds solution for binary effect efficiency measures. J Public Health. (2021) 30:2059–68. doi: 10.1007/s10389-021-01587-x

Crossref Full Text | Google Scholar

40. World Health Organization (2002). Active ageing: A policy framework. WHO/NMH/NPH/02.8 Geneva. Available at: https://www.who.int/ageing/publications/active_ageing/en/

Google Scholar

41. World Health Organisation. Global age-friendly cities, a guide. Geneva: World Health Organization. (2007).

Google Scholar

42. Kalache, A. The Longevity Revolution: Creating a society for all ages. Adelaide Thinker in Residence 2012–2013. Adelaide: Government of South Australia (2013).

Google Scholar

43. World Health Organization (2015). World report on ageing and health. Geneva: WHO. Available at: http://apps.who.int/iris/bitstream/10665/186463/1/9789240694811_eng.pdf (Accessed December 2019).

Google Scholar

44. Eckermann, S. Policy implications and applications across health and aged care reform with baby boomer ageing—from age and dementia friendly communities to palliative care. Chapter 12 In: E Simon, editor. Health Economics From Theory to Practice: Optimally Informing Joint Decisions of Research, Reimbursement and Regulation with Health System Budget Constraints and Community Objectives. London: Springer (2017). 279–320.

Google Scholar

45. McCaffrey, N, and Eckermann, S. Raise the Bar, not the threshold value: meeting patient preferences for palliative and end-of-life care. Pharm Econ Open. (2018) 2:93–5. doi: 10.1007/s41669-017-0039-y

PubMed Abstract | Crossref Full Text | Google Scholar

46. Eckermann, S. Globally optimal trial design and risk sharing arrangements are key to avoiding opportunity costs of delay and enabling equitable, feasible and effective global vaccine research and implementation in current or future pandemics. Front Public Health. (2022) 10:1085319. doi: 10.3389/fpubh.2022.1085319

PubMed Abstract | Crossref Full Text | Google Scholar

Keywords: opportunity cost, net benefit, threshold value, health shadow price, budget constrained optimization, allocative efficiency, displacement efficiency

Citation: Eckermann S (2024) Aligning opportunity cost and net benefit criteria: the health shadow price. Front. Public Health. 12:1212439. doi: 10.3389/fpubh.2024.1212439

Received: 26 April 2023; Accepted: 21 February 2024;
Published: 06 March 2024.

Edited by:

Hai Fang, Peking University, China

Reviewed by:

Guvenc Kockaya, ECONiX Research, Analysis and Consultancy Plc., Türkiye

Copyright © 2024 Eckermann. This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY). The use, distribution or reproduction in other forums is permitted, provided the original author(s) and the copyright owner(s) are credited and that the original publication in this journal is cited, in accordance with accepted academic practice. No use, distribution or reproduction is permitted which does not comply with these terms.

*Correspondence: Simon Eckermann, seckerma@uow.edu.au

Disclaimer: All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article or claim that may be made by its manufacturer is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.